00:01
Welcome back to your online presentation of
macroeconomics.
00:05
My name is James DeNicco and this
presentation will be talking about growth.
00:09
When I talk about macroeconomics, there's
not too many topics that are more important
than growth. So let's get into it.
00:17
What are we going to be learning here?
Well, what questions are we trying to answer
about growth?
First, what are the sources of economic
growth?
What policies can increase economic growth,
and why are there such large
differences in living standards around the
world?
That's what growth is about.
00:34
Growth is about evolving standards of
living.
00:38
So how does a nation's growth rate evolve
over time?
What is the relationship between a nation
standard of living, their population
growth, their savings rate and technology?
Those are the factors.
00:50
Those are the variables we're going to
concentrate on.
00:53
So we'll poor countries catch up to rich
countries or will the
disparity widen over time?
That's what we're going to focus on as well,
something called the convergence literature.
01:05
The answer is it depends.
01:06
It depends on the country.
01:08
If their character characteristics are
similar to those richer countries, they're
most likely going to catch up.
01:13
If not, those disparities could widened over
time.
01:17
So why do we care about growth?
Well, like I said, we care because it's
about evolving standards of living over
time. If you take a look at these pictures
here, it's very poignant.
01:28
We're trying to take children who live like
this here and evolve their
countries so that they can have better
lives, they can be happier children like
this. Nobody wants to see children starving.
01:38
Nobody wants to see children deprived.
01:40
We want to afford our children every
opportunity to be able to fulfill their
aspirations and their life dreams.
01:46
That sounds touchy feely, but that's what
growth is about.
01:50
It's about giving people opportunity.
01:52
That's why so many people concentrate on it.
01:54
That's why so many people care about it.
01:56
It is one of the main focuses of
macroeconomics trying to make
people's lives better.
02:02
Trying to evolve these standards of living.
02:04
Trying to have children not look like this.
02:07
Trying to have children look happy like
this, to give people a chance.
02:11
That's what growth is.
02:12
That's what growth is to me.
02:14
So you see, I get excited when I talk about
it because I think it's an important topic.
02:18
So what are the different factors that it
can allow us to increase countries
standards of living, allow them to evolve
their standards of living over time?
Well, standards of living in production go
hand in hand.
02:30
So how can we increase the income per
person, which is our measure of standard of
living. Our standard of living measures, GDP
per capita.
02:38
So we take the wealth or income in an
economy and we divide it by the number of
people. And that's our average income per
person.
02:46
That's our measure of our standard of
living.
02:49
We're also it's also a measure of
productivity.
02:51
How productive is an economy?
The more productive an economy is the higher
standard of living they're going to have.
02:57
So we're going to talk about some of these
factors of growth and productivity.
03:01
The first one is physical capital.
03:04
So physical capital is a tangible asset used
by firms in
production. It includes a number of things
our factories, our
machines, our tools, our equipment, our
computers, all these things
we can use to make our workers more
productive.
03:20
So you take a guy and you tell them you want
them to go outside and break up a slab of
concrete. Well, if he's using his hands,
it's going to be a hard job, right?
If you give him a sledge hammer, he's going
to be able to do it.
03:33
It'll be more productive.
03:34
He'll be able to break up that concrete.
03:37
Now let's give him a jackhammer.
03:39
Let's give him some better physical capital.
03:41
Now that jackhammer, he's going to be much
more productive in breaking up
that slab of concrete.
03:47
We become better and more efficient at our
jobs where we're given the proper tools
and equipment or we're given physical
capital to accomplish those jobs.
03:57
So that's our first factor in growth and
evolving standards of living.
04:02
We also have human capital.
04:04
So human capital encompasses our education,
our health and
our training. So how healthy and how skilled
are our workers?
The more skilled a worker in he is, the more
productive he is, the better he is at his
job. So the more skilled worker he can earn
more income, right?
You can earn more overall income, which
increases that GDP per capita and
raises those standards of living.
04:28
We have more productive workers when they're
skilled as well.
04:33
When they're healthy, the healthier worker,
the better they are.
04:36
Everybody's been sick out there.
04:38
When you try to do a task, when you're sick,
you find it's much harder.
04:42
So this plays into health care policy and
the health
of a nation. How healthy are the workers?
How healthy is the workforce?
In most of our developed countries, that's
not as big of a deal.
04:53
But in a lot of our underdeveloped country
countries where diseases like AIDS run
rampant, it's hard to have a productive
workforce with a high standard of living when
people are worried about their health and
they can't get healthy to even go to work.
05:07
So our human capitalists are second factor
of growth.
05:11
So our next one are our natural resources.
05:13
That's another factor of growth.
05:16
So the more natural resources an economy
has, the higher the standard of living
can be, the higher the income per person can
be.
05:24
Now, that's one a lot of countries can
control the natural resources that they have,
the coal in the ground or the oil in the
ground or the land that they have for
grazing or open waterways.
05:35
So they have access to to clean and open
water.
05:39
It's hard to control whether you have these
things.
05:42
You can control the policies of whether you
access them or not, but you can't really
control whether you have these natural
resources.
05:49
But if you do, if you're a country that is
lucky enough to have them, it can increase
your income per person and increase the
standards of living and increase your
productivity. Our next factor of growth is
entrepreneurship.
06:02
So the people that are willing to take the
financial risk for the financial reward of
profit, these are innovators.
06:09
These are people that go out there and they
work and they become productive for that
financial reward.
06:15
Do you have those entrepreneurs out there?
Your social and legal framework, that's
another factor.
06:21
So is your government and your society set
up to incentivize this
entrepreneurship? Does it foster
entrepreneurship?
Does it foster productivity?
Are the rules in place to allow standards of
living to increase over
time? And lastly, our most important one,
technology
we'll see out of a star of the technology.
06:42
That's because it is the most important.
06:45
Over time, that's our best way to increase
our standards of living.
06:49
It touches all of our other factors.
06:52
So when you think about physical capital,
technology can make our physical capital
better. You go from the sledgehammer to the
jackhammer.
07:00
Our technology increases.
07:01
We become more productive.
07:03
You think about human capital, our education
with the advent of the
Internet and computers and all the
technology that we have.
07:11
Sharing knowledge is so much easier.
07:13
We're doing this online course in the
seventies.
07:17
This online course will be very difficult to
do.
07:19
But now we have these capabilities so that
we can share our knowledge and become more
skilled. When you think about your natural
resources, we have concerns about
environmental degradation when we go when we
access those natural resources.
07:33
But with technology, we can access them
cleaner and we can access them better and we
can use them more efficiently.
07:39
Used to only be able to drill one way down.
07:42
Now you drill for oil.
07:43
They can drill down over, up, around and
curlicues, whatever they want.
07:47
It's amazing the technology that exists out
there to access these natural resources.
07:52
Entrepreneurship, technology effects.
07:55
Entrepreneurship. You can start a business
online now, so it's easier to be an
entrepreneur. So technology, it just it
touches all these different
factors of growth.
08:05
So that's the wild card.
08:07
That's the most important one.
08:08
And that's what will give you long lasting
increases in our standards of living or long
lasting economic growth.
08:15
So let's get to our model.
08:17
So to model economic growth, we're going to
be using what's called the solo growth
model. Some people call it the neo classical
model.
08:25
So this is the base model for a lot of the
literature.
08:29
I'd say the large percent of literature out
there right now that focuses on economic
growth. It was developed by a man named
Solow.
08:37
That was his last name.
08:38
So he gets credit for the model, of course,
the solo growth model.
08:42
So first, we're going to define our terms.
08:44
We're going to give a functional form.
08:46
We're going to give an equation for our
standard of living to see how we can increase
our standards of living over time.
08:53
So here we're going to have a lowercase y
equals a times or lowercase k
raised to the alpha.
09:00
So let's go through these terms first.
09:03
Why that's GDP per capita.
09:06
So as GDP divided by the number of people,
if you remember, GDP
was our production, it was also our income,
it's also our expenditures.
09:16
So GDP is overall income in economy.
09:19
Gdp per capita is the average income per
person.
09:23
That's going to be our measure of our
standard of living.
09:26
What does it depend on?
It depends on this uppercase, A, which we
call total factor productivity.
09:33
So total factor productivity, the main
driver of it is
technology, but it's also going to include
entrepreneurship, social and legal
framework, natural resources, human capital.
09:45
You can look all that into there.
09:47
It's whatever isn't captured by our
lowercase K here.
09:51
Our lowercase k is going to be our capital
per person or our
capital to labor ratio.
09:58
Here. We're going to assume, for
simplicity's sake that everybody in the
economy works.
10:04
So our GDP per capita is also our labor
productivity,
GDP divided by the number of workers.
10:11
What's our income per person?
What's our productivity per worker?
It's the same thing in this model because we
assume that the population
equals the workforce.
10:22
Everybody's working.
10:24
So our lowercase k now is going to be our
capital to labor ratio.
10:28
It's also going to be our capital per
person.
10:31
So again, our standard of living, which is
measured by our GDP per
capita and GDP per worker, is going to be
our total factor
productivity times, our capital labor ratio
or our capital per
worker raise to the alpha.
10:46
We'll talk more about this Alpha in a
second.
10:49
Alpha is going to be between zero and one.
10:51
It's going to give us the shape of our
growth function.
10:55
It's going to allow the shape to have what
we call diminishing returns.
11:00
So let's take a look.
11:02
What does this look like?
Well, this is our standard graph here.
11:05
So on our vertical axis, we're going to have
our our standard of living or our GDP per
capita on a horizontal axis.
11:13
We're going to have our capital to labor
ratio.
11:15
So obviously, physical capital per worker
here, that's the main variable we're looking
at. So how does the standard of living and
how does GDP per capita, how does
productivity increase as the capital to
labor ratio
increases? What you see here is this curve
flattens out.
11:34
That is due to the fact that Alpha is
between zero and one.
11:38
It's what we call diminishing returns.
11:42
So holding all else, constant holding our
labor force constant
as we increase physical capital.
11:49
How much more productive does our economy
become?
We assume these diminishing returns, which
are empirically a valid assumption,
we see that out there in the empirics, we
assume these diminishing returns which
drive a lot of our results.
12:06
So what do diminishing returns do?
What you're going to see is as we increase
the capital per worker, we're
always going to have an increase in
productivity.
12:16
But the size of the increases is going to
get smaller and smaller
and smaller.
12:22
Those are the diminishing returns.
12:25
We're going to have increases in
productivity, but the size of the increases
gets smaller. If you take a look here, we
have this first increase in our unit of
capital up to this line right here.
12:36
So if you take a look at the vertical axis,
you see this large
increase in productivity with that first
unit.
12:45
But because that shape, that curve flattens
out.
12:49
The second increase, the second unit of
capital is going to
increase production, but by a much lesser
amount.
12:57
We see here with the with the label of
second unit, this
size increase is much smaller than the first
increase that's due to that
flattening out or those diminishing returns.
13:09
So what's the intuition behind that?
So you take a farmer and he has to till his
field by land.
13:16
Just one farmer.
13:17
We're going to hold that constant.
13:18
He's doing all the work by hand.
13:20
You give that farmer one tractor.
13:23
How much more productive is.
13:25
Is he now? He goes from using his hands the
till of the land to do all the work he needs
to do to now he has a tractor.
13:31
It takes him way less time to do.
13:33
His work is leaps and bounds.
13:35
Are the increases in productivity with that
first tractor?
Now remember, we're going to hold the number
of workers constant here so that capital per
person is increasing because we're
concentrating on the capital ratio.
13:49
So now the farmer goes and gets himself a
second tractor.
13:53
He's only going to use that tractor when the
first one is down.
13:57
It's in the shop, or maybe it needs to
refuel or something.
14:00
When he can't use the first one, he will use
the second one.
14:04
So he's obviously more productive.
14:05
There's no downtime.
14:07
You always has a tractor to do his work, but
most of the time that tractor,
that second one is sitting there idle.
14:14
So the increase in production isn't as much
as the first one.
14:17
The first one, he went from nothing to a
tractor.
14:20
The product, the productivity increases were
huge.
14:22
The second one, the productivity increases
are much more modest because most of
the time the second tractor is sitting there
idle.
14:30
It's not being used.
14:31
He only uses it in times when the first one
is down, when the first one is in the
shop so that he is more productive.
14:38
He can always work now, but the increases in
production gets smaller and smaller and
smaller. That's the intuition behind
diminishing returns.
14:46
So we assume these diminishing returns in
our solo growth model.
14:51
So if increases in the capital labor ratio
are important, we should
talk about how we increase the capital to
labor ratio.
15:00
Well, we increase it through investment.
15:03
So we're all in per capita terms here.
15:05
So when I say investment, we're in the lower
case, it's investment per person.
15:09
So as we know from our GDP lecture, part of
investment is purchasing
physical capital.
15:15
So we purchase physical capital through
investment.
15:19
So as we increase our investment, we
increase our physical capital
per worker. How does the physical capital
per worker decrease over
time? It's through what we call effective
depreciation.
15:32
So here we're going to have our endless
Delta Times K.
15:36
So that is the decrease in the capital to
labor ratio through
the population growth rate and and the
depreciation rate
delta. So why do we need both the population
growth rate and the
depreciation rate?
Well, we're in per person terms.
15:54
So as the population growth rate rises,
capital per
person is going to be diminished.
16:00
It's going to go down.
16:03
We need the depreciation rate because we're
dealing with physical capital.
16:06
That capital you can think of is wearing
away over time.
16:09
The equipment is going to wear down over
time as you use it.
16:13
So there's going to be a depreciation or
wear down rate on that physical
capital as you use it.
16:20
So we're going to have increases in physical
capital with investment.
16:24
We're going to have the decreases in
physical capital per person, all in per
capita terms with effective depreciation.
16:32
So what is our investment?
Our investment we're going to define as our
savings rate times
GDP per capita.
16:42
We're going to assume that investment equals
savings here.
16:45
We're going to close the economy and we'll
talk about this more in our later series.
16:50
But here we assume savings equals
investment.
16:52
So every dollar you put in the bank, a firm
or a business is going to borrow that
money and they're going to buy physical
capital with it.
17:00
So the savings rate times our income, a
percentage of our
income we're going to save and that's going
to be used for investment.
17:10
So that's why we have this little s are the
savings rate times our income per
person. Now we can take that a step further.
17:18
We know our income per person is our total
factor.
17:22
Productivity times, our capital labor ratio
raise to the alpha,
right? If we went back a few slides, we
would see that that's what we define
GDP per capita.
17:33
So these are the same equations.
17:36
I'm just elaborating on an equation one
investment minus effective
depreciation. In equation two, investment is
just the savings
rate, times the income per person.
17:47
So the amount of savings per person, that is
our investment.
17:51
And now I just replace the income per person
with the equation that we defined
it as total factor productivity times the
capital ratio raised
to the alpha. This is how our capital labor
ratio changes over
time. We can put this on a graph.
18:09
Sometimes seeing it makes it make more
sense.
18:12
So let's do that.
18:13
Let's go to the solo growth model.
18:16
So here's your basic solo growth model we
already saw before our GDP
per capita. It increases with those
diminishing returns.
18:26
What does our investment line look like?
What does our investment curve look like?
It looks just like our GDP per capita curve
is just smaller
because it's the same curve, but it's just a
percentage of that curve.
18:38
It's the savings rate, times that GDP per
capita.
18:42
So it's just smaller.
18:45
Our effective depreciation rate that has a
linear curve
that increases linear linearly.
18:52
So the fact that we have these diminishing
returns in growth and
investment, but a linear increase in
effective depreciation is going to
drive the results of this model.
19:04
It's going to allow us to come to what we
call our steady state.
19:08
Our steady state is always going to be where
our effective depreciation
curve intersects our investment curve.
19:16
So let's talk a little bit more about that.
19:19
First, what we see here is we're going to
see y minus i equals c.
19:22
So what we're saying is there's no
government spending in this model.
19:25
We're going to assume that away as well.
19:28
So all we're going to have here is investment
and consumption.
19:31
So before GDP, where we had GDP equals
consumption plus
investment plus government spending plus net
exports, we're going to assume away
government spending in net exports per.
19:43
Now, you can put those back in later if you
want to make it more complicated.
19:47
But for simplicity's sake, to understand the
basic intuition and the model, we're going to
assume those away.
19:53
So we're going to see part of our GDP per
capita is our savings or our
investment. The rest of it is going to be
our consumption.
20:01
So again, we have our GDP per capita line
here equals total factor
productivity times the capital labor ratio.
20:09
That's how the standard of living evolves
over time.
20:12
So how does the capital labor ratio evolve
over time?
It evolves with investment, which also has a
diminishing return, and investment in
turn depends on income per person.
20:24
So we use a bit of our income per person.
20:26
We save it. When we save it, we invest them
by more physical capital.
20:30
We buy more physical capital, we become more
productive.
20:33
We increase our income per person as our
income per person increases.
20:37
We can save a bit of that.
20:39
We can invest more and buy more physical
capital.
20:41
It's a cycle that goes on and on as you move
to the right on the graph.
20:46
And it happens up until the point where
effective depreciation
intersects with investment per capita.
20:54
There's our steady state.
20:56
We can find our steady state at the
intersection.
20:58
This is our steady state capital to labor
ratio.
21:01
We draw the line up where that intersection
takes place.
21:05
We go over to our horizontal axis.
21:07
That's our investment per capita steady
state.
21:10
If we go up to our standard of living steady
state, our GDP per capita steady
state, our labor productivity, steady state,
they're all the same thing.
21:19
We've made it so so that they're all the
same.
21:22
We go over to the vertical axis.
21:24
That's our standard of living per capita.
21:27
That's where we get stuck.
21:28
We get stuck at this point.
21:30
What's going on at this steady state?
Well, let's take a look to the left of the
steady state.
21:35
So remember, our change in capital is our
investment per person,
minus our effective depreciation.
21:43
So when investment per person is greater
than effective depreciation,
we're going to be growing.
21:49
We're going to be moving to the right here
when this investment curve is
greater than effective depreciation, we're
going to be growing and moving to
the right now if we're to the right of the
steady state.
22:02
And again, the change in the capital ratio
equals investment minus
effective depreciation.
22:09
If this effective depreciation curve is
greater than investment, we're going to be
moving back to the left.
22:16
So intuitively, what's going on here?
Well, let's start over here where we're the
capital labor ratio is lower than the steady
state. So we have a certain income per
person.
22:26
We use a percentage of that income per
person for investment.
22:30
We buy more physical capital, we add more
physical capital.
22:34
We become more productive.
22:36
We're more productive.
22:37
We have more income per person.
22:39
We have more income.
22:40
We can invest more.
22:41
We can buy more physical capital.
22:43
We have more physical capital become more
productive.
22:46
We have more income.
22:47
We can invest more, we can buy more physical
capital.
22:49
It goes in a cycle.
22:51
So we keep moving to the right towards that
steady state.
22:56
However, because of diminishing returns, the
increases in productivity,
the increases in income per person, the
increases in investment per person are
getting smaller and smaller and smaller, so
that by the
time we hit our steady state, the increase
in capital which
increases income per person, is just enough
to buy
capital to replace what's depreciated away.
23:23
We have just enough money.
23:25
We're making just enough money to replace
our worn down or used our
equipment, our factories, our machines and
our tools.
23:34
We have just enough money to keep up with
what we have at that
steady state. We can't break that steady
state unless there's a change
in one of the variables that dictate our GDP
per capita.
23:48
Where our investment per capita.
23:50
Things like total factor productivity or the
savings rate.
23:54
That's how we can break that steady state
and move further to the right.
23:59
You'll notice it's steady state.
24:01
If you look back at the equation, what we're
saying there is the capital to labor
ratio is zero for the changes in the capital
labor ratio or zero
because investment equals effective
depreciation.
24:14
Again, the change in the capital labor ratio
equals investment minus
effective depreciation.
24:20
You look at these this graph right here,
that's where these two curves intersect.
24:25
That means investment and effective
depreciation are the same.
24:29
So the change in the capital labor ratio is
zero.
24:32
We get stuck at this steady state.
24:35
So that's what the steady state is all
about.
24:38
Now there's this convergence literature that
evolves
from the solo growth model.
24:46
So what is the convergence literature?
Will poor countries catch up to rich
countries?
Well, there's two general theories on this.
24:52
One is unconditional convergence.
24:55
So you can read the words, you can read the
definition.
24:57
But basically it says poor countries are
going to catch up to rich countries no matter
what. So if you look in the graph, what does
that mean?
You'll see a country here, K rich and K
poor.
25:09
They're both away from the steady state.
25:11
K poor is further away from the steady
state.
25:15
The further away you are from the steady
state, the faster you're going
to grow towards that steady state.
25:22
You'll see. I drew lines in here that are
tangent to the slope of our
income per person.
25:29
So if you like calculus, if you take a
derivative of that line, that's the growth
rate, the slope at that point.
25:36
So I'm drawing in the slope at that point,
you'll see for the poor
country, the slope is steeper than the slope
for the rich country.
25:45
That steeper slope indicates faster growth.
25:48
So the poor country is going to catch up to
rich country, to the rich country when they
hit their steady state.
25:55
That unconditional convergence says that
that is definitely going to happen.
26:00
But what that assumes is that the two
countries have the same steady state.
26:04
Unconditional convergence has been shown to
be quite false.
26:08
Now, conditional convergence, on the other
hand, says that poor countries will catch
up the rich countries, if they share similar
characteristics, that
one bears out much better.
26:20
So if you take a look at all the countries
out there and plot GDP per
capita versus growth rates, you're not going
to see
that smaller levels of GDP per capita
correlate to
higher growth rates because that's what the
solo growth model says.
26:37
It says the lower your GDP per capita, the
higher your growth rate.
26:42
Now, if you take similar countries or say
you take the states within the United States
and you plot that on a graph, you will see
that.
26:49
You will see that countries with lower GDP
per capita have
higher growth rates.
26:55
The states with lower GDP per capita are
catching up to the states with
higher GDP per capita.
27:02
So again, unconditional convergence.
27:05
Poor countries will catch up to rich
countries.
27:07
Conditional convergence, poor countries will
catch up the rich countries if they
share similar characteristics, those similar
characteristics being total
factor productivity, the savings rate, the
population growth rate and the
depreciation rate, all those things that
decide where the steady
state is. So that's our convergence
literature.
27:30
So what effects will we have with an
increase
in the savings rate?
Let's now focus on these different factors
that decide our steady state.
27:40
Let's focus on these different factors that
decide our standard of living.
27:44
We'll focus on the savings rate first here
we want to know a few questions about it.
27:49
So what are the short and long run effects
on the growth rate with an
increase in the savings rate?
And then lastly, what are the effects on
consumption?
Because that's important, because we all
want to consume, whether it's for survival or
for utility, to make ourselves happy, we
like to consume.
28:07
So here we're going to assume that the
savings rate goes up.
28:10
We're going to have an S two greater than an
S one, a savings rate
to greater than savings rate one.
28:18
So what's that going to look like on the
graph?
Let me show you. An increase in the savings
rate is going to shift
up. The only line with an S in it is the
savings rate goes up.
28:31
You're going to see a higher level of
investment per capita at
every point along that graph.
28:38
So the savings rate goes up, it shifts that
steady state to the right.
28:43
We have more investment per person.
28:45
We have more physical capital.
28:47
So that increases our productivity again.
28:49
So now we have more income again.
28:51
So now we can buy more physical capital and
we can continue that cycle
for a longer period of time until again, our
effective depreciation
overwhelms our investment and we get stuck
at a new steady state.
29:06
That higher savings rate allows for a higher
standard of living.
29:10
So what are the short and long run effects
on growth?
In the short run, as that steady state moves
to the right, you're going to have
positive but diminishing growth.
29:21
So again, we're moving along this curve
here.
29:23
You jump from here up to here and grow to
the right.
29:26
As you grow to the right, you have positive
but diminishing growth.
29:30
Again, that's the short run.
29:33
In the long run, you hit your new steady
state and the growth rate
goes back to zero.
29:40
The effects on consumption with an increase
in the savings rate are ambiguous.
29:45
We don't know.
29:46
We know now that our GDP per capita or
income per person has gone
up because we increase the savings rate so
we have more money to buy stuff.
29:56
But at the same time, we're saving a larger
percentage of our income.
30:01
So it depends on which one of those factors
overwhelm.
30:04
If the increase in income is enough to
overwhelm the increase in the savings
rate, than consumption will go up.
30:11
If the increase in income isn't enough to
overwhelm the fact that you're saving a
larger percent of your money, well, then
consumption is actually going to
go down. So if you have $100 in, it
increases the $200.
30:26
Obviously, you can buy more stuff if your
savings rates stay the same.
30:30
If your savings rate goes up too much, well,
then you're not going to be able to
consume as much as you were before.
30:37
So it depends on which one of those factors
overwhelm.
30:40
So again, the short and long run effects,
with an increase in the savings rate,
we're able to buy more physical capital and
become more productive.
30:49
Now we can break our steady state and steady
state moves to the right.
30:53
We'll grow in the short run with positive
but diminishing returns until
we hit our new steady state.
30:59
And the long run, we are at a pretty steady
state.
31:02
The fact is depreciation has overwhelmed
investment per person.
31:07
So now we're stuck at that new steady state.
31:09
The growth rate goes back to zero.
31:12
Consumption is ambiguous.
31:14
It depends on whether the increase in income
overwhelms the increase in the savings rate
or the increase in the savings rate over
well overwhelms the increase in income
per person. So that's our savings rate.
31:26
So we see that we can increase our standards
of living with an increase in our savings
rate. However, it's bounded, you can't save
more than
100% of your money.
31:36
So in the long run, increasing the savings
rate is probably not the way to go
if you want these long run increases in your
standard of living.
31:45
It's bounded.
31:46
And on top of that, who wants to save 100%
of their money?
What's the point of making money if you're
going to save all of it?
You want to consume some of your money, so
you're going to have an unhappy population
out there if you're saving 100% of every
dollar you make.
32:00
So that brings us to our next factor, total
factor productivity.
32:05
Now, let's take a look at this.
32:06
What happens if total factor productivity
goes up?
We're going to go from a one to a two here
with a two being higher than
a one. So what's that going to look like on
our graph?
Well, every line when total factor
productivity in it is going to shift up,
say it's an increase in technology.
32:26
Right. Where all of a sudden more
productive.
32:28
We're more productive.
32:30
So we can increase our income per person as
their income per person goes
up. We can invest more and buy more physical
capital.
32:38
Again, we can break that steady state as we
have more income, more capital.
32:42
More capital makes us more productive.
32:45
More productive. We have more income, more
income.
32:48
We can buy more physical capital.
32:49
You get back in that cycle of those
diminishing returns for a longer period
of time. Now you break that steady state and
you move to the right.
32:59
So again, in the short run, it's going to be
the same effect as the increase in the
savings rate. It's going to be positive, but
diminishing returns.
33:08
As we move to the right, though, we will hit
our steady state at some point further down
the road. Now, when we hit that steady state
where our effective depreciation
overwhelms our investment per capita, we'll
get stuck again.
33:21
So our long run, our growth rate will go
back to zero.
33:26
So in the short run, positive, but
diminishing returns.
33:30
In the long run, our growth rate goes back
to zero.
33:34
What are the effects on consumption?
Well, they're unambiguously positive.
33:38
We know what's going to happen.
33:40
Consumption per person is going to go up.
33:43
We have more income per person and we're
saving the same percentage amount of money.
33:48
So if we have $100 now and we're saving 50%,
that means we're
consuming $50.
33:55
If it goes up to $200 and we continue to
save 50% of our
money, now we're consuming $100.
34:02
We went from 50 to 100.
34:04
We know there's going to be an increase in
consumption per person with an increase in
total factor productivity.
34:11
So if you think back to our factors of
growth, we were talking about it, put a
little star there on technology.
34:17
Technology is the main driver of total
factor productivity.
34:21
Total factor. Productivity is unbounded.
34:24
It's constrained only by the human
imagination.
34:27
The human imagination is unbounded.
34:29
It's unconstrained.
34:30
So we could always increase our total
factory productivity.
34:34
We can always increase that.
34:36
So we can continually move to the right and
drive up our standard of living.
34:41
Total factor productivity and technology are
the key to
unbounded long term economic growth.
34:50
So we've covered the savings rate.
34:52
We've covered total factor productivity.
34:55
Now let's cover the population growth rate
so this can apply to both the
population growth rate and the depreciation
rate.
35:02
So here we're going to have the population
growth rate and to greater than our
population growth three and one.
35:09
So what happens is the population growth
rate goes up in the solar growth model.
35:14
Well, we're going to see that line bend up
from the origin.
35:19
That straight linear line is going to move
up to the left.
35:23
What that means is our steady state is going
to move to the left as well.
35:28
So we're going to have negative growth to
our new steady state until we
hit that steady state, that lower steady
state, and our growth rate goes back to
zero. That's because the capital labor ratio
has to go down its
capital per person.
35:44
So as the population growth rate goes up,
capital per person will come
down. Just like if the depreciation rate
went up.
35:52
If Delta went up, then you're going to have
a decrease in the capital per person and
a lower steady state.
35:58
So you'll have negative growth back to the
left until you hit your new lower
steady state, at which point the growth rate
goes back to zero.
36:07
So this might be a flaw in the Slow growth
model.
36:10
There's not a definite correlation between
population growth rates and growth.
36:14
Sometimes you see it countries that are
poorer have higher population growth rates.
36:18
But at the same time, higher population
growth rates mean more people, which mean
more brains.
36:24
As we know more brains, we can have more
innovation and increases in total factor
productivity. So that is one question about
the Solow growth model.
36:33
All these models aren't perfect, but if they
were perfect else, economists would be out of
job. So thank goodness they're not perfect
so we can continue to develop them.
36:43
So that brings us to the end of this
presentation.
36:46
What we've talked about here, we know the
sources of economic growth, why it's
important to develop and evolve these
standards of living for countries over time.
36:56
We know how to construct and graph that solo
growth model.
36:59
The Solow growth model is the model we're
using here for growth.
37:04
We've learned about diminishing returns and
how poor countries can catch up to rich
countries. And we learn that total factor
productivity is the key to
sustained long term economic growth.
37:15
Again, it's unbounded because it's only
constrained by the human imagination.
37:19
And the human imagination is unbounded
itself.
37:23
Things we're doing today, technologies
today, even 20, 30 years ago were unthought
of, except by a few brave and innovative
entrepreneurs that make things
happen. So that's your growth presentation.
37:36
Thank you.