00:01
Hello and welcome back to your
onlinepresentation of microeconomics.
00:05
My name is James DeNicco, this
presentation is going to be about externalities.
00:10
We're gonna learn what externalities
are and why we care about them.
00:13
They introduce inefficiencies into the market.
00:16
We're gonna look at what policies
we can take to address externalities
and what are some private solutions to
externalities and when do those solutions break down?
So first, what is an externality?
An externality is the uncompensated impact of
one person's actions on the wellbeing of a bystander.
00:34
So what are some examples of
these externalities? One is pollution.
00:38
So you have these smoke stacks, they create a negative
externality because people have to breathe in the air.
00:45
Now it's costly for firms to retrofit for production, retrofit
their smoke stacks to reduce pollution, so they don't.
00:52
So that leaves a role for government
to come in and regulate that pollution
because the they have the
uncompensated impact on bystanders.
01:01
That's a negative externality.
01:03
An example of a positive externality
might be a restored historic building, right?
It conveys a positive externality cause
people enjoy the beauty and the history.
01:12
However, the owner doesn't get the full
benefit and is too quick to tear the building down,
it's gonna cost them a lot to retrofit and to fix that
building so that other people can appreciate the beauty.
01:24
He incurs all the cost but he has to share the benefit so
sometimes it's not worth it to him to restore that building.
01:31
So there is a role for government
you can come in and you can subsidize.
01:35
You can say, "hey, here's the money to help restore that building
because it conveys this positive externality to everybody.".
01:41
Another externality is a dog
barking, that's a negative externality.
01:46
It's your dog, you bought the dog but
there's an uncompensated third party.
01:49
That's the person that
has to listen to the dog bark.
01:52
Alright, that pollutes his air waves and not like a smoke
stack but it pollutes his air waves in that he has to hear that
that conveys a negative externality on him.
02:01
That's uncompensated, so now there's
a role for government to come in and say,
"hey, you have to stop that dog from
barking, you have to bring it inside.
02:09
If you can't control it, you'll
have to get rid of the dog.
02:12
Another example of an
externality is research, alright?
Research conveys a positive externality
because it creates these new technologies
that everybody can use that increases our knowledge.
02:24
However, sometimes there's not a lot of incentive to do
research if people can just go ahead and take what you've done.
02:31
You don't get to capture the full benefit.
02:33
You incur the full cost but you
don't get to incur the full benefit
so sometimes there's not enough incentive to
go out there and do research and development.
02:41
So you can have government policies
that encourage it, you can give patents
that allow people to get the full
benefit of the research development
and therefore they'll go
out and be willing to do it.
02:53
So we have all these different examples of
these externalities and they leave a role for policy,
so let's take a look at some of the policies we
can implement to address these externalities.
03:04
You basically have two types.
03:06
You have command and control policies, those
right to use of regulation, you say you do this or else
or you can have market-based policies, those are
encouragements, right it's the carrot and the the stick.
03:18
It's alright if you do this, we'll give you
this, otherwise we're gonna wack you.
03:22
Alright, taxes and subsidies.
03:26
So first the command and
control, alright - regulation.
03:29
You can think of the Environmental
Protection Agency, alright they tell you,
hey you can't go ahead and dumped that stuff in
a river, that's just a command and control policy.
03:38
That's regulating that externality that's saying,
hey you can't impact these people this way
or you have to go ahead and you have to retrofit
your smoke stacks to reduce your carbon footprint
because you're costing society too much.
03:52
You have all these uncompensated
people being impacted by your actions
so you can have that direct
heavy-hand, that command and control
or a market-based policy would be a corrective tax.
04:06
It's a tax to induce private decision-makers, it's to
encourage them to take account of the social cost
okay, that arise from
these negative externalities.
04:17
So what's an example of when
we can use this corrective tax?
Well when there's a negative externality, so
let's take for example the aluminum market.
04:25
So you have a firm that's producing aluminum,
so the producer doesn't consider the total cost.
04:31
They just consider their internal, their private cost.
04:35
So we have prices in quantity here where these
green lines come together, our supply and demand.
04:41
This is the demand for aluminum and the green
line is the supply just looking at the private cost.
04:47
Well there's the uncompensated third parties
here from the pollution of producing the aluminum.
04:52
There's too much aluminum being produced.
04:55
The actual cost is the social
cost plus the private cost
so you have to find a way to force
the firms to internalize that cost.
05:04
One way you can do it is by instituting the tax.
05:08
Now if you do it just right, you'll institute
a tax which is the size of the social cost,
the external cost plus the social cost
then you'll be at the social optimum.
05:18
You'll shift that supply curve to the left
because it's more costly for the firm to produce.
05:23
They'll produce the lower quantity
which is in line with the social optimum.
05:28
You can also have subsidies,
this is another market-based policy
so if there's some sort of positive externality
from some sort of action, you want to encourage that.
05:38
And you can encourage that by subsidizing
production, so let's take a look at what that looks like.
05:44
So here now, we have our demand, right?
This is the private value, this is the private
value, say it's robot production here in our example.
05:54
So the firm doesn't consider the external benefits of robot
production which is discovery of new and better technologies.
06:02
Right, they do too little of it
compared to the social optimum.
06:07
The social plan of the government, they can come in
and they could try to fix that problem with the subsidy.
06:12
So you're gonna see here again,
we have our price and our quantity,
we have our private value and we have the supply.
06:19
However the total value is greater than the private
values, the private value plus the external benefit.
06:26
So how do you encourage more robot production?
Well you can go ahead and
you can subsidize the production,
you can make it cheaper for
them to produce the robots.
06:36
That'll shift the supply curve to the right and that'll
increase the amount produced up to the social optimum.
06:43
So when it's a negative externality, you want to
put a tax in place to try to discourage production,
want to decrease production to get to the social optimum.
06:54
When it's a positive externality, you want more of
it, you would encourage it by subsidizing production
so that they produce more and
they'll increase to the social optimum.
07:04
Sometimes you don't need the government
involved, sometimes private solutions work.
07:09
So what are some examples of private solutions? Well
sometimes we have these moral codes and these social sanctions
like parents teaching their kids
not to litter, right cause littering,
that has an effect on an
uncompensated third party.
07:23
So we teach our children, we
teach them not to do these things.
07:26
That's one way to address these externalities.
07:29
You also have charities like the Sierra club,
they raise money to try to protect the environment,
or you can rely on self-interested parties,
right, so the self-interest of relevant parties.
07:41
So let's take an example of somebody who has an
apple orchard and another person who is a beekeeper.
07:47
They're side-by-side, one grows the apple tree, sells
the apples, the other has the bees so he can make honey.
07:54
Alright, now the bees and the apples, they
provide a positive externality for each other.
08:00
So the trees, they provide nectar for the
bees so the bees can eat and they can flourish.
08:06
The bees, they pollinate the
trees so they help the trees.
08:10
So the beekeeper and the person who owns
the apple orchard right, they incur the total cost
but they share the benefit so
sometimes they'll underproduce.
08:23
So now what can happen is, you can
have an integration of the businesses.
08:27
You could have, say the beekeeper the
apple orchard owner, they can look and say,
"Well, I'm not producing enough, he's not
producing enough because we benefit each other,
so maybe if I buy both businesses, I can
produce more apples and I can have more bees
because we're helping each other out, we're producing
enough to convey that positive externality to each other".
08:47
or if not, I can have one guy buy the business, you can
have a social contract or you can have a private contract.
08:52
You can contractually agree to produce more so
that both of you doing it and you help each other out.
08:58
So these contractual agreements or just the integration
of businesses, can sometimes address these externalities.
09:07
However, private solutions don't always work
out, so we have what's called the Coase Theorem.
09:12
That's the proposition that private parties can
bargain without cause over the allocation of resources.
09:18
They can solve the problem, the externalities on their own.
09:21
The trouble is, sometimes, there's cost
involved, there's transaction cost involved.
09:26
So let's take an example here of the
barking dog, we have neighbor Bob.
09:30
He's sick of neighbor Chip's dog barking, says "I will
give you $50 to get rid of that barking dog of yours".
09:37
Right, this is a private solution.
09:39
Chip's a little offended, "How dare you put a dollar value on
my dog, I won't get rid of him for a penny under a hundred"
So he has neighbor Bob say, "Deal, I would
have given you $150 to get rid of that dog"
Right so there's some consumer
surplus there, so that will work out.
09:57
Right, you can take care of that
externality by getting rid of the dog
But if there's transaction cost,
sometimes that can get a little messy.
10:08
Say we have neighbor Chip now, he says,
"well, turns out only my mom will take the dog
and it will cost me $100 to ship them,
so now I need $200 to get rid of the dog".
10:20
Neighbor Bob was only willing to pay $150, the
transaction cost got in the way of that private solution,
so it didn't work out.
10:28
So you know sometimes,
bargaining just breaks down as well.
10:31
So a deal would you be possible but finding
the right price for both parties can be difficult.
10:36
It's difficult to come to that solution and the more
parties involved in the deal, the more that it can go wrong,
so these private solutions are
sometimes difficult but they do exist.
10:47
So what have we learned here?
We know what externalities are, and they know
how they introduce inefficiencies into the market.
10:54
We understand the difference
between command and control policies,
command and control, it's like
the EPA Regulation, you do this.
11:01
We have the market-based policies
with our taxes and our subsidies,
and we also understand how private solutions
can sometimes address these externalities
but sometimes they break
down because of transaction cost.
11:13
So that's your presentation
on externalities, thank you.