00:01
Welcome back to your online presentation of
macroeconomics.
00:05
My name is James DeNicco.
00:06
This presentation will be about CPI,
inflation.
00:10
CPI is the Consumer Price Index.
00:13
So as the name portends, we're going to be
looking at how consumer prices change
over time.
00:19
This is the second of our three major
macroeconomic variables we're going to look
at that we use to measure the health of the
economy low and relatively
stable. Rates of inflation are actually
considered healthy for the economy, but too
much inflation, inflation, there's costs
associated with that.
00:36
So we want to understand those costs.
00:39
So what are we going to be looking at in
this presentation?
Well, we're going to look at what the CPI
is, exactly how we measure the
CPI. We want to know how you calculate
inflation using the
CPI. There's problems with the CPI.
00:54
It's not perfect. Again, it's another
manmade measure like GDP.
00:59
We have accounting rules that we're subject
to when we calculate the CPI.
01:04
So it's imperfect.
01:05
We want to understand those imperfections.
01:08
We're going to look at what the costs of
inflate inflation are.
01:11
Why do we care about it?
And finally, what's the main culprit of
inflation?
I'll give you a little bit of foreshadowing.
01:18
It's the printing of money.
01:19
Usually runaway inflation is highly
correlated with the printing of
money. So let's get into it first.
01:26
What is CPI?
Again, it's always nice to start with the
definition.
01:30
So for any given period, the CPI measures
the cost
in that period of a standard basket of goods
and services
relative to the cost of a basket of goods
and services in a fixed year
called the base year.
01:46
That standard, the word standard is very
important here.
01:49
We're going to keep a consistent basket over
time so we can see how the prices change
for the same goods.
01:56
And we're going to have that all relative to
this base year.
01:59
We're going to fix the year.
02:00
We'll say this is the year we want
everything relative to how do prices change
compared to that year.
02:06
So our equation for the CPI, it's going to
be the price in the current
year of that standard basket of goods
divided by the price of that
same standard basket of goods in our base
year times 100.
02:20
Again, like when we use the GDP deflator,
the Times 100 just turns it into
an index for us.
02:26
So if the CPI is above 100, that means there
has been
inflation compared to the base year.
02:35
The GDP deflator was the other measure that
we use to look at inflation,
CPI we're looking at now.
02:41
They're a bit different. There's other
measures of inflation as well.
02:45
So what are the differences between the GDP
deflator and the CPI?
Well, the GDP deflator looks basically at
the prices of production.
02:54
The GDP deflator is subject to the rules of
GDP.
02:58
So how do the prices of production goods and
services go up over
time? The CPI, as I said, is the Consumer
Price Index,
so it doesn't care about the rules of GDP,
the GDP deflator.
03:11
It's everything produced within our borders.
03:13
The CPI doesn't care where something is
produced.
03:16
If you're buying at the supermarket, they
want to know about it.
03:19
It's a measure trying to look at the normal
goods and services that we all buy in
our daily lives to see how those prices go
up over time.
03:28
So how we're affected in our normal lives
and our purchasing by the increase in
prices. So again, the GDP deflator is
subject to the rules of
GDP. The CPI is looking only at consumer
goods, what
you buy no matter where it was produced.
03:45
So how do we calculate the CPI?
First, we want to fix our basket.
03:49
That's very important.
03:51
Obviously, if the basket change is what
we're calculating in the prices of
changes, the price of the basket is going to
change.
03:58
So we want to keep that consistent over
time.
04:01
So if we have eggs and bread and milk, just
those three items in
our basket one year, we just want eggs and
milk and bread in that
basket. The next year, if we allow that
composition to change, of course there's
going to be a difference in the price.
04:17
There's a difference in the value of
different goods.
04:20
So we want the same goods with the same
value and look at how those prices
change over time.
04:26
So we fixed that basket.
04:28
So that gives us our consistent measure over
time.
04:32
Next, we want to find the prices.
04:35
So the Consumer Price Index in the United
States is calculated by the Bureau of Labor
and Statistics.
04:41
Literally, they go out and they find out the
prices of all these different thousands of
items in the store. And look at the price
tag.
04:48
How much does that item cost?
So they go out and they find the price of
the different items in that standard
basket of goods.
04:57
So then they calculate the price of the
basket of goods.
05:01
Now that we found all the items that we're
going to have in there, we fixed our basket.
05:05
We found the price, the price of all those
goods.
05:08
Now we're going to calculate the cost of the
whole basket.
05:12
Finally, we compute our index again.
05:15
Our CPI equals the price of our standard
basket of goods in
our current year divided by the price or the
cost of our standard
basket of goods in our base year.
05:26
So it's all relative to that base year.
05:29
Our price is going up.
05:31
Relative to that base year.
05:32
We multiply it by 100 to put it into our
index.
05:37
So let's do an example here.
05:38
First, we need to fix our basket of goods.
05:41
So in this example, I just have three goods.
05:44
I have one time rent of a two bedroom
apartment.
05:49
I have 60 hamburgers and I have ten movie
tickets.
05:53
Now, I guess we'll say this is per month.
05:55
That's a lot of hamburgers in a month.
05:57
But I like hamburgers, so we'll go with it.
05:59
I'm eating 60 hamburgers a month.
06:00
It's all on me. We only have three goods in
here, so we fixed our standard
basket of goods. Then we go out and we find
our price.
06:08
So we have our prices.
06:10
In year 2000, the rent for our two bedroom
apartment is $500.
06:15
Each of our 60 hamburgers cost $2 and our
movie tickets, they cost
$6. Then in 2005, we're going to want to do
the same
thing. We keep our basket the same the same
goods in there so we don't change that
composition. So we're looking how the price
has changed for those same goods over
time. In 2005, our our rent for our two
bedroom
apartment is $630.
06:41
Our hamburgers now cost $2.50 and our movie
tickets
cost $7.
06:47
Well, now that we fixed our basket and we
found our prices, we can calculate the
cost of that basket.
06:54
It's very simple.
06:56
So our bedroom, our rent here in 2000, one
times 500 is
500. Our 60 hamburgers times $2 is $120.
07:05
Our ten movie tickets times are $6 is $60.
07:09
You add all those up and what you get is
$680.
07:14
Our standard basket of goods and 2000 is
$680
for 2005.
07:21
Again, the same goods one time rent of a two
bedroom apartment
times $630 is 630.
07:30
Our 60 hamburgers times are $2.50 is
$150 are ten movie tickets.
07:38
Times are $7 comes out to $70.
07:41
You add all those up.
07:43
And now our standard basket of goods is gone
from $680
to $850.
07:49
So now we can calculate our CPI.
07:53
We need to pick a base year.
07:55
So here we'll pick your 2000 as our base
year.
07:59
So that's the year everything's going to be
relative to.
08:02
So if we want to calculate our CPI or our
consumer price index, it's the
price in the current year over the price and
the base year times 100.
08:11
Just like with the GDP deflator, our index
in the base year is always going to be
100 because the price is in the current year
and the and the base year for our standard
basket of goods is the same.
08:23
Now for 2005 here, our price in our current
year is
$850. The price in our fixed year, our base
year is
$680. So 850 divided by 680
times 100 is 125.
08:39
So compared to our base year, we see that
there's been some inflation,
125 is greater than 100.
08:47
So prices for that standard basket have gone
up over time.
08:51
So now that we've calculator CPI, we can
look at how we calculate
our inflation rates.
08:58
So how do we do that?
Well, it's going to be a percent change
again, just like with the GDP deflator, it
will be CPI in your T minus CPI in your T
minus
one divided by CPI in your T minus one times
100.
09:13
In other words, if we're using the inflation
rate from 2000 to
2005, you want the CPI in 2005 minus the CPI
in
2000 divided by the CPI in 2000 times 100.
09:27
So what was the inflation rate?
What was the percent change in the CPI from
2000 to
2005? Well, here it's a pretty easy example,
125
-100 divided by 100 times 100.
09:41
Our inflation rate was 25% over five years.
09:46
So this is a quote that I like.
09:48
Inflation is when you pay $15 for the $10
haircut you used to
get for $5 when you had hair.
09:56
I always like to talk about that and because
it makes me feel good thinking about myself
relative to my brothers.
10:01
So it's nice to see my brothers.
10:03
They're starting to lose their hair.
10:04
I can shave mine because I know it's always
going to come back.
10:07
I have a nice full head of hair, so I like
to show this to my brothers to remind them
that they're going bald while I keep my
hair.
10:15
You have to have fun with economics.
10:17
So let's do some more examples.
10:20
Let's calculate some more inflation rates.
10:22
All right. So let's look at the inflation
rate from 1931 to 1932 in the
United States.
10:28
So here, these are real numbers.
10:29
I went and pulled them from the Bureau of
Labor and Statistics.
10:32
So from 1931 to 1932, let's take a look.
10:36
We have a CPI in 1931 of 15.2.
10:40
We have a CPI in 1932 of 13.7.
10:45
So to calculate our inflation rate, we just
say CPI, T minus
CPI, T minus one over CPI, T minus one times
100.
10:53
Here we're just going to have 13.7
-15.2 times 15.2 times
100. We see that the inflation rate is
negative nine.
11:06
That's negative inflation.
11:08
It's what we call deflation.
11:10
So that's an example where the price level
for our standard basket of goods has gone
down over time.
11:16
The CPI also allows us to have some fun
games.
11:19
All right. So when your grandfather
complains about how so small his
starting salary was compared to your
starting salary, you can fact check your
grandpa. You can take a look and see in real
terms if he's telling the
truth. Of course, he made less in nominal
terms in dollar figures.
11:37
Of course he's going to make less starting
out compared to what you're going to make
starting out because there's inflation over
time.
11:44
So what would your grandfather's salary be
in today's terms?
So let's do a little example.
11:50
So in year 1972, we have a CPI of
41.8. Your grandfather's starting salary was
$25,000
in 2013.
12:01
The CPI is 130.
12:03
Your starting salary is 75,000.
12:07
Obviously, in nominal terms, in dollar
terms, 75,000 is
greater than 25,000.
12:14
But what about in real terms how much stuff
you can buy?
That's much more important than the dollar
figure is how much stuff you can buy.
12:22
So let's turn Grandpa's $25,000 into today's
terms
to see who is actually doing better as far
as purchasing power goes.
12:33
So there's two ways you can do this.
12:35
There's the longer way, and then there's a
shortcut.
12:38
The shortcut works because the long way
works, so we'll go through both.
12:42
So you would want to use your CPI equation
and solve for your missing
variable. So you have your grandfather's
25,000, you
know, the CPI is 41.8.
12:54
You know the equation to find out the CPI,
it's current year of that
basket of goods divided by the base year
times 100 equals
41.8. So what we would need to do is find
the
salary in the base year for your
grandfather.
13:11
So when we solve that, we would find that
the base year is
59,809, just using a little bit of algebra.
13:20
So now that we have the base year salary for
your grandfather, we can take that and
turn it into year 2013 terms.
13:28
Again, using the equation of the CPI.
13:31
Now we have the base year.
13:33
We know the CPI in 2013, we can find the
wages in 2013.
13:38
So just using a little bit of algebra again,
we find out that in purchasing
power terms, your grandfather was making
$77,752.
13:49
He was actually doing better than you with
your starting salary of 75,000.
13:54
He was able to make more stuff than, buy
more stuff than you, so he was
actually better off than you.
14:01
So there's a shortcut to doing this as well.
14:04
So if you're calculating this, you don't
have to go through those two steps.
14:08
You can use ratios to solve this much
quicker.
14:12
And it works because everything is relative
to our base year.
14:15
So you don't have to go through these two
steps.
14:18
What you can do is say the dollars in one
year over the CPI in
that year has to equal the dollars in
another year over the CPI in
that other year.
14:28
So you can set it up like this.
14:30
So your 25,000 over your CPI of
41.8 has to equal that 25,000 in
2013 terms over the CPI in 2013 of
130. Again, you just use a little bit of
algebra and you'll find the same
answer. Your grandfather's wage was
$77,750. So you can say, Relax, Grandfather,
I'm
not making any more than you in real terms.
14:59
You are actually doing better in what you
can purchase than I was.
15:03
So a little bit of fun with the CPI there.
15:07
So policymakers actually use the CPI.
15:10
They use it for something called indexing.
15:13
Now, indexing is when you tie a nominal
benefit to an
inflation rate.
15:18
So why would you want to do that?
So you're receiving some sort of benefit,
say, in the United States, it's Social
Security. So when people reach a certain
age, they paid into Social Security and
they get a certain amount of money from the
government each month or each period.
15:35
So you want that real benefit to stay the
same over
time. If it was $100 you were receiving over
time as there's
inflation, that $100 can buy less and less
amount of stuff.
15:49
So you want to go ahead and you want to tie
that benefit to an
inflation rate.
15:55
So in nominal terms, the benefit increases
at the same rate of
inflation, so that in real terms it stays
the same.
16:04
You're able to buy the same amount of stuff
over time.
16:08
So again, the nominal quantity that's in
current dollars, the real
quantity, that's the amount of stuff you can
buy, which is much more important than the
actual dollar figure.
16:18
If you're making $100 and everything costs
$2, that's much better.
16:23
If you're making than if you're making $100
and everything costs $10, you're able to
buy a lot less stuff as inflation goes up.
16:31
So they have this practice of indexing.
16:34
The trouble with indexing to the CPI, which
is what the United States
government ties Social Security to, is that
the CPI overstates
inflation. So now we're going to talk about
some of the flaws in the
CPI because we have this fixed basket of
goods.
16:51
This measurement isn't perfect over time
because it can account for changes in
people's behavior.
16:57
The first problem with the CPI is this
substitution bias.
17:01
We have this standard basket of goods, so
that standard basket of goods
doesn't allow us to account for people's
change of behavior.
17:10
So there's probably a lot of coffee drinkers
out there.
17:13
So say you go to the store to get your cup
of coffee and coffee has gone from
$2 to $15.
17:20
Well, there's some of you that may be very
loyal to your coffee.
17:23
You're going to get your coffee anyway.
17:25
So I'm not talking I'm talking to everybody
else who normally sees the prices go up.
17:30
We're going to change our behavior.
17:32
We're going to substitute away from that
coffee.
17:35
We're not going to stop drinking our
caffeine because we need our caffeine.
17:38
Without our caffeine, where it will be big,
we'd have no energy left.
17:42
Right. But we're not going to keep drinking
coffee when it's going from $2 to
$15 a cup we might substitute to tea.
17:50
We'll start drinking more tea, which is
cheaper.
17:53
Well, that standard basket of goods doesn't
allow that.
17:55
If the basket says you drink ten cups of
coffee at $2 is going to say you're
drinking ten cups of coffee at $15.
18:03
It doesn't allow that substitution, which is
going to exaggerate inflation.
18:08
In reality, you're probably not drinking ten
cups of coffee anymore.
18:12
You're maybe drinking five cups of coffee and
five cups of tea at that
lower price. So your general spending, the
inflation isn't going to be as much
as it looks like with the CPI.
18:24
It doesn't allow for that change in people's
behavior.
18:28
It doesn't allow for the substitution that
we see that takes place.
18:32
We have that fixed basket of goods.
18:34
We're subject to those accounting rules.
18:36
So that's the first problem of the CPI and
that overstates inflation.
18:41
The second problem with the CPI is what we
call the quality adjustment bias.
18:46
So say you have a computer in 1970 in the
basket and a computer in
2014 in the basket was going to say, there's
a computer, there's a computer.
18:55
Maybe in 1970, it cost $1,000.
18:58
In the year 2014, it cost 1200 dollars.
19:01
But the computer in 2014 is way more
powerful than the computer in
1970. My phone is probably more powerful
than the computer in
1970. It doesn't see that increase in the
quality of that good.
19:14
It just sees the increase in the price.
19:17
But the value of the good is going up.
19:19
So it's going to overstate inflation.
19:21
So the people that measure this inflation,
they've tried to take steps to correct this.
19:26
So they'll take a computer and they'll take
the different parts of it.
19:29
They'll say the ram or the gigs, the memory,
the speed.
19:32
But look at those individual parts instead of
just a computer here and a
computer there. So they attempt to fix these
problems.
19:41
But the problem still holds with some goods.
19:43
If you have a good in the past versus good
in the future, they won't see the quality
adjustment or the increase in the value of
the good.
19:50
In the future, they'll only see the increase
in the price.
19:53
So again, it's going to overstate inflation.
19:56
The third problem, which also overstates
inflation, is what we call the introduction
of new goods buys.
20:02
Again, we have the standard fixed basket of
goods we don't allow.
20:07
It's in there. But with new technologies and
new goods, we usually see an
efficiency and efficiency with that
technology that allows us to have better,
higher quality goods at lower cost.
20:18
It doesn't allow for that.
20:20
So it says you can't substitute to these new
goods.
20:23
It's like the substitution bias.
20:25
But with this with these new goods, with
these efficiencies from technology.
20:29
So it doesn't allow for these lower cost,
more valuable goods to be in that
basket. So, again, it's going to overstate
inflation, whether it's the
substitution bias, the quality adjustment
bias or the introduction of new goods
bias, it's going to overstate inflation.
20:46
Now, when you're indexing benefits to the
CPI, that's going to cause a
problem in real terms.
20:53
People's benefits are going to be increasing
over time.
20:56
If you tie the nominal or the dollar figure
of those benefits to inflation, as
inflation rises in real terms, the benefit
goes up and they can buy more
stuff. If you're the one receiving the
benefit, you probably don't see that as a
problem. But if you're the people paying for
the benefit, that is a problem.
21:12
You're looking to keep the benefit in real
terms the same over time.
21:16
You don't want it to increase over time.
21:18
So those are the flaws with our man made
measure of the CPI.
21:23
So now why do we care about inflation?
What are the problems?
Inflation? Well, if there's too much
inflation, we're going to see cost to the
economy. The first is what we call our shoe
leather cost.
21:34
And it comes from the fact that you're
walking around with money in your pocket.
21:38
So your shoes, if they're made of leather,
shoe leather costs.
21:41
So I have a dollar here.
21:44
All my money is big dollar I'm walking
around with in my pocket.
21:48
So as I have this dollar in my pocket and I
walk around, inflation's taking
place. The purchasing power of this dollar
is being eroded.
21:56
So if candy bars cost $0.50 today, I can get
two candy bars with my
dollar. If tomorrow, candy bars cost $0.55
today, now I can only
buy one candy bar with my dollar.
22:09
I need to find some more money to get that
second candy bar.
22:13
And it's especially acute with the money in
your pocket as opposed to money you might
keep in your savings account.
22:19
Because in your savings account, at least,
you're earning interest to combat those shoe
leather costs.
22:25
Normally, interest rates are associated with
price levels.
22:29
So as prices go up, what you'll see the
Federal Reserve in the United States or the
central bank in any country, the Central
Bank of Europe, they're going to
try to raise interest rates to combat
inflation.
22:41
So at least as there's inflation and shoe
leather costs that are eroding the purchasing
power of the dollar, your interest rates
will go up and you'll be sheltered from some
of those shoe leather costs.
22:52
Your money will be increasing with the
interest rate to combat the
erosion of your purchasing power.
22:58
So that's the first cost are shoe leather
costs.
23:01
Our second cost here are distortions in the
tax system.
23:05
So as inflation goes up, what you're often
going to see is
firms are going to increase your nominal
wages that keep your real wages
the same. So they're earning more for their
products.
23:19
So they're going to want to keep your real
wages or your purchasing power the same.
23:23
So they'll increase your nominal wages to
keep your real wages the same
so that you don't become dissatisfied and go
look for work somewhere else.
23:32
The problem with that is it can bump you up
into higher tax bracket.
23:36
So what that means is the government will be
taking a larger percentage of your money
in real terms. You're able to buy the same
amount of stuff with that more money.
23:45
But now the government comes and takes a
larger percent in taxes.
23:49
So actually you're able to buy a lower
amount of stuff because of that inflation.
23:54
You're getting bumped up into that higher
tax bracket and that's costing you.
23:58
That's our second cost of inflation.
24:01
We also have what's called our unexpected
redistribution of wealth.
24:05
So we have banks out there and banks they're
going to set their nominal interest rate
or the interest you'll pay on a loan.
24:12
It's based on the real interest rate plus
what they expect inflation to
equal. This is called our Fisher Equation.
24:20
So you have the banks, they say, hey, I'm
going to make this guy alone.
24:24
I wanted to figure out how much interest he
should pay monthly on that loan.
24:28
I'm going to take a look at the real
interest rate right now and what I expect
inflation to be.
24:34
And that's what he's going to pay me per
month on that loan.
24:38
However, when the realization of those
payments come, it's no longer expected
inflation. It's what actual inflation is.
24:45
So the real return or the real interest rate
that they're earning
on that loan equals the nominal interest
rate minus the
actual inflation rate.
24:56
So the actual inflation rate is higher than
what they expected it to be.
25:01
Their real return is going to be lower.
25:03
Now, that's good for the people that took
the loan out.
25:06
The banks who gave the loan, that hurts
them.
25:08
That hurts their balance sheets.
25:10
Now, some people might have little sympathy
for the banks, but if the banks are losing
money, they're going to have to find a way
to make that up through fees or through
whatever else. Or they're going to be less
likely to hand out loans.
25:22
So you don't want the banks to be in a bad
position, even though some of us might not
have that much sympathy for the banks.
25:29
So you had your shoe leather costs.
25:31
Now you have your unexpected redistribution
of wealth.
25:34
We also had our distortions in the tax
system, our cost of inflation.
25:40
Our last cost here is our noisy signal.
25:42
What the noisy signal is when firms look out
there and they see prices going up,
that can mean there's also higher demand.
25:50
As demand increases for a good or service,
the price is going to go up.
25:55
However, that's not always the reason why
prices are going up.
25:58
Say there's too much money printing going
on, so there's just inflation across the
board. Well, firms might misinterpret that
increases inflation as an
increase in demand.
26:08
So what they'll do is they'll ramp up their
production.
26:12
But if there's no increase in demand, that
production is going to go on sold.
26:16
They're going to produce be producing more
goods when they shouldn't be.
26:20
That will cost them. It'll just be sitting
on their cell- shelves as inventory.
26:23
They might have to lower the price of those
goods, get rid of them.
26:26
So that's our that's our cost of inflation
through the noisy
signal noisy signal, because they're having
a hard time interpreting that
signal. Now, what's the cause of inflation?
Oftentimes, the cause of inflation is going
to be printing the money.
26:42
We see very strong linkages are very strong
correlations between the printing of
money and inflation.
26:49
So we have some examples of this throughout
history in times we call hyperinflation.
26:54
Hyperinflation is a very, very bad and
destabilizing thing for an economy.
26:59
You take a look at post-World War one
Germany, and you saw this
hyperinflation after the war.
27:06
They had to pay back these reparations, all
these countries, they couldn't keep up.
27:10
So they started printing money.
27:12
So as they started printing money, price
levels got out of control to the point where
the currency became almost worthless.
27:19
I have a picture here of a woman burning
money to stay warm because the money
wasn't able to buy anything.
27:26
It got to that point where people were just
throwing money away.
27:28
There's pictures of children playing the
stacks of millions of dollars because the
money is worthless.
27:34
That's a very destabilizing for an economy.
27:37
And then you also have Zimbabwe in the
2000s.
27:41
So you had what you call the million dollar
economy, or people would go to the
store, they would go to the market.
27:48
And in the morning you have a loaf of bread
that costs thousands of Zim
dollars. And then in the afternoon it caused
millions of Zim dollars.
27:56
By the next day, it costs billions of
dollars to the point where the money again
was worthless and people weren't even
accepting the money.
28:04
So in order to be able to buy something,
people would have to go pan for gold in the
rivers. If you couldn't find gold that day,
you weren't eating.
28:12
So there's very bad consequences to this
hyperinflation.
28:16
That's why we want to understand it and we
want to know what goes into it so that we can
combat those bad consequences, so that we
can try to prevent this
hyperinflation. Mm hmm.
28:27
So that was our presentation.
28:30
What did we learn?
Well, we know the definition and the
accounting rules for CPI.
28:35
We know how to calculate CPI, and we know
how to calculate inflation rates
using CPI.
28:42
We knew how to use the CPI to compare
nominal quantities over time or real
quantities over time.
28:49
We know how the CPI has a tendency to be
biased towards overstating
inflation and we also learn the cost of
inflation.
28:56
The reason we really care why we use this
macroeconomic variable to
measure the health of the economy because
there's costs associated with it.
29:05
Thank you very much.