00:01
Welcome back to your online presentation of
macroeconomics.
00:04
My name is James DeNicco.
00:06
This presentation will be about consumption
and savings.
00:10
So over the next few presentations, we're
going to be talking more specifically about
the different components of GDP.
00:17
Here we'll be talking about consumption, of
course.
00:20
So what exactly are we going to be doing?
We're going to be looking at what savings
is.
00:25
So there's this relationship between savings
and consumption.
00:29
The more you consume now, the less you can
save now, the more you save now,
the less you can consume now.
00:35
So we'll be looking closely at that
relationship.
00:38
We're going to be using what's called the
two period consumer model to do that.
00:42
We'll also be looking at the relationship to
income and savings and consumption.
00:47
As your income changes, how does that change
the relationship between consumption and
savings? And we'll also be taking a look at
interest rates and how changes in interest
rates incentivize you the more savings or
more consumption now.
01:02
So first, let's take a look at some
definitions.
01:05
So we'll define savings.
01:07
So here, savings is specifically going to be
your current income minus
your current consumption.
01:14
So if we're talking annually, it will be
this year's income, minus this
year's consumption.
01:20
Savings is what we call a flow variable.
01:22
It's measured per unit of time.
01:24
Whatever you define that unit of time to be,
if it's weekly, it's my
income this week, minus my consumption this
week.
01:32
That's specifically what savings is here.
01:35
That's what we're going to define it as.
01:37
Wealth. That's different than your savings.
01:39
Wealth is a stock variable, so your savings
now will turn into part of your
wealth later on.
01:46
Your wealth specifically, again, are your
assets minus your
liabilities, your total assets minus your
total liabilities,
your savings rate.
01:56
That's going to be your savings divided by
your income.
01:59
So the percentage of your income that you're
saving, capital gains and
capital losses, those are changes in the
value of your assets.
02:08
So a capital gain, that's when there's an
increase in the value of your assets.
02:12
Your stocks go up or you earn interest on
your savings.
02:15
You call it your savings account.
02:17
But really, maybe it should be called your
wealth account because again, savings are
specifically your current income minus your
current consumption.
02:25
Next period after that flow variable is
measured in this period, next period, that'll
be part of your wealth.
02:31
So capital gains are increases in the value
of an asset.
02:34
Capital losses are decreases in the value of
an asset.
02:38
So if you have a retirement plan and there's
some sort of crisis that goes on,
a financial crisis like in the United States
in 2008, and a lot of people lose
value on the retirement plans that would be
a capital loss.
02:51
So one more time, your savings is a flow
current income minus current
consumption. Your wealth is a stock
variable, your total assets minus your total
liabilities. Your savings rate is the
percent of your income that you save.
03:06
Capital gains are increases and the value of
your assets and capital losses
are decreases in the value of your assets.
03:13
So now that you understand the definitions,
let's go forward and look at the life
cycle of savings.
03:20
So you see here in this graph, what we have
on the vertical axis is your
income and your consumption.
03:27
Along the horizontal axis is your life line
or your age.
03:31
So we're going to take a look at this line
right here, this horizontal line that's
constant across the graph, that's
consumption.
03:39
What that's showing is consumption is
balanced over time here.
03:43
It's constant over time.
03:44
That's not necessarily the way it's going to
be.
03:47
We have a theory called the consumption
smoothing theory that I'll get to in some
later slides. That's what you want smooth
and balanced levels of consumption over
time. It doesn't have to be constant,
however, but for purposes of this graph, we
draw a constant.
04:01
Now the line that goes up and down, that's
going to be your income.
04:05
So what you're going to see is early on in
your life, you're going to be spending more
than you bring in. That's a period of
dissavings.
04:13
So probably a lot of you out there might
have some student loans or you're taking
loans out on your cars or some of you have
mortgages you need to pay on.
04:22
So you're spending more than you're bringing
in right now.
04:26
But as you move along, you get to your prime
earning years.
04:29
This actually makes me feel a little bad
because I guess I should be in my prime
earning years. I hope that's not the case
yet.
04:34
But as you move along here, you see you
start to earn more than you spend.
04:39
So you're saving.
04:41
So what you're saving for is when you get to
later in your life, say, around
65, you retire.
04:46
You want that nest egg, you want the money
to live out the rest of your life.
04:51
So once you hit about 65, again, you're
dissaving you're spending the
money that you saved during your prime
earning years.
04:59
So that's what the.
05:00
Savings lifecycle looks like for most of us.
05:03
It may be shifting to the right these days a
little bit.
05:06
I don't know. We'll see.
05:09
All right. So why do you save whatever
motivations for saving?
Well, one or long term goals, things like
you want to buy a house, you want to buy a
car, you want to go on a nice vacation.
05:19
A lot of us don't have the money just
sitting around to do those things.
05:22
So we have to set a plan.
05:24
We have to save to reach those goals.
05:27
Or it could be precautionary savings.
05:29
You never know when something's going to
come up.
05:31
You get sick or you get hurt.
05:32
You have to spend money on hospital bills or
you can't go to work.
05:35
They usually say you should have about six
months worth of income sitting in your
savings account for precautionary reasons.
05:43
Also bequest or inheritance.
05:45
Most of us hope we have parents that love us
out there and a lot of our parents, they want
to earn money so that they can leave
something behind for their children.
05:53
Inheritance. Or if you're a philanthropist,
you have a lot of money.
05:57
You want to leave your legacy behind.
05:59
You want to leave money to different causes
or different universities.
06:02
That's another reason to save these bequest
savings.
06:06
So those are our three main reasons to save
your money.
06:10
So now let's talk about our model, our two
period consumer model as the
name portends.
06:16
There's only going to be two periods in the
first period.
06:19
You're going to have resources and you're
going to have uses.
06:22
In the second period.
06:23
Again, you're going to have resources and
you're going to have uses.
06:27
So what we call these our budget
constraints, our first period and second
period budget constraints, your uses are
constrained by your
resources. So in the first period you're
going to have this term A, that's initial
wealth. So where does that come from?
Well, you can use your imagination.
06:45
It's dropped out of helicopters from the
sky.
06:47
You just have a certain initial amount of
wealth.
06:50
You also earn an income in the first period
y one.
06:54
So those are your resources, your uses.
06:57
In the first period, you can consume that C
one or you have
b b is going to be your wealth that you
carry between periods.
07:05
It's almost savings.
07:07
If A were equal to zero, it would be savings
because then y one minus C
one would equal B, but since we have this
initial wealth, it's not exactly
savings. It's going to be your wealth
carried over.
07:20
So then in the second period, what do we
have?
We have our income.
07:23
In the second period, we have the wealth
that we carried over and we have
any interest that we earned on that wealth.
07:30
So you'll see one plus R times B one times B
that's you getting your
wealth back and our times.
07:37
B, that's the real interest that you earned
on the wealth that you carried
over your uses in the second period.
07:45
It's just consumption.
07:46
You're not going to save any more money
because after the second period we assume
that you die. That's a little drastic.
07:53
I know, but it's a simplification for the
model.
07:56
So if that makes you sad, I apologize.
07:58
But that's the way we're going to set up the
model after the second period.
08:01
You die, so there's no reason to save after
that point.
08:04
So this is your first period and your second
period of budget constraint.
08:08
All right. So let's move forward with the
model a little bit so we can combine
these two budget constraints into our
lifetime budget constraint.
08:17
So we can have one simple equation that we
can graph and take a look at the
incentives of changes in income and changes
in interest rates on our consumption
and saving patterns.
08:28
All right. So there's one term in common
between these two budget constraints.
08:32
That's our B, that's our B variable, our
wealth carried over.
08:36
So what we're going to do is we're going to
take the first period of budget constraint
and we're going to solve for B, when you
solve for B, it's a plus Y
one minus C one.
08:46
There you can see it's very close to our
savings.
08:48
If A were zero again, B would be our
savings.
08:52
Now that we solve for being the first period
budget constraint, we're going to take it and
we're going to stick it into the second
period budget constraint.
09:00
So where do you see the B in the second
period of budget constraint?
You're going to replace it with what we
solved for B in the first period budget
constraint, and then we're going to combine
it all together.
09:11
So when you do that, what you see is C2
consumption.
09:15
The second period equals Y2 plus one plus R
times B
which is now a plus Y one minus C1.
09:24
We can rearrange this a little bit so that
now we'll have the present value of lifetime
resources on the left and the present value
of lifetime consumption on the
right. So what is this present value term I
talk about?
Well, let's take a look here.
09:38
So you don't need to discount A or Y one
that's already
in the present, but a value that you're
going to have in the future.
09:47
You need to discount that by the interest
rate because to have
1000 in the future, you don't have to have
1000 now because you can earn
interest on money.
09:57
You need to have x times the interest.
10:00
Rate equals 1000.
10:02
So x the value that you need now equals that
1000 divided by
the interest rate you need.
10:09
Whatever value multiply by that interest
rate will give you 1000 in the
future. So we turn that into what we call
net present value.
10:17
So you'll see the net present value of y two
is divided by one plus R,
and the net present value of lifetime
consumption on the right hand side are
uses that see one which is already in
present value terms and the
discounted C two So you divide that by one
plus R or the interest rate.
10:36
All right. So now we have our lifetime
budget constraint.
10:39
We have the resources on the left and the
use is on the right.
10:44
So now we're ready to move into a graph
which sometimes helps make this make
sense for everybody. When you put it in
graphic terms, something you can look at.
10:53
So here's what it looks like.
10:55
It's downward sloping.
10:56
So we have C two on the vertical axis and we
have C one on the horizontal
axis. You'll notice the more you spend in
the second period, the less you can
spend in the first period.
11:06
The more you spend in the first period, the
less you, the less you can spend in the
second period.
11:12
So we have this line that goes down anywhere
along this budget constraint,
and that's what that line is.
11:18
It's our budget constraint.
11:19
It's feasible you can spend on any one of
those points.
11:23
It's possible we call this guy the super
saver up here, the guy that spends
nothing, nothing in the first period and
saves everything for the second period.
11:31
He's the guy you don't want to hang out
with.
11:33
He's never willing to pitch in.
11:34
When you go out to lunch, he's the guy that
always forgets his wallet.
11:38
You have the guy c one here.
11:40
He's the party animal.
11:41
He spends it all now and leaves nothing for
later.
11:44
He's probably fun, but later on he's
probably going to have to come back to you
and ask you to pay for lunch.
11:49
All right. Most of us aren't those people.
11:51
Most of us are somewhere in the middle
that's due to what we call the
consumption smoothing theory or the desire
of households to maintain
a smooth and balanced level of consumption
over time.
12:04
So I'm kind of famous in my classes for what
they call the consumption smoothing dance
because I try to do a little dance to help
them remember, and it kind of goes like this.
12:12
I say, You got to smooth your consumption,
so I'm embarrassing myself and doing
the dance for you.
12:18
Not quite as dramatically as maybe as I do it
for them.
12:21
Maybe we'll do an abbreviated one, but we
like to smooth our consumption out over
time. All right.
12:27
We want these smooth balance levels.
12:29
We don't like big interruptions to our
consumption patterns.
12:32
So now any point inside the budget
constraint is possible, but it's
inefficient. That would be like you have
money left over, you're going to die after
the second period, but you don't spend the
money.
12:43
That makes no sense.
12:44
So you don't want to be in there.
12:45
You're going to spend all that money.
12:47
It's inefficient to be inside the budget
constraint.
12:50
Now, outside, that's not feasible.
12:52
You can't be there.
12:53
Your budget doesn't allow you to get there.
12:55
So somewhere along that budget constraint,
we're going to be in that area.
13:01
So now let's take a look what happens if
there's a change in income, if you have an
increase in income, whether it's in this
period, whether it's in next period, the
first period or the second period, you're
going to see an increase in consumption in
both periods.
13:15
That, again, is because we want to smooth
out that consumption.
13:19
If we earn more money now, we don't want to
spend it all now we want to spend some of it
now. We want to save some to spend some
later.
13:27
If we earn more money later, we know more
money is coming.
13:29
We don't want to spend it all later.
13:31
We want to smooth out our consumption.
13:33
We want to pull some of that consumption
forward.
13:36
So we're going to save less.
13:38
That's a parallel shift in the budget
constraint to the right.
13:41
So you'll have more consumption in both
periods.
13:46
It looks like this.
13:47
So I like to use these arrows.
13:49
I think it makes the most sense when you
talk about the two period consumer model.
13:53
So an increase in current income, you're
going to see an increase in the first period.
13:57
You have more money now you're going to
spend some of it.
14:00
Now you're also going to increase your
consumption next period.
14:04
So in order to do that, you need to save
some of the money that you make.
14:08
Now, say your boss gives you a $100 bonus
right now that would mean you
spend 50 of it. Now you save 50 of it to
spend 50 of it later
if your income is going to go up in the
future, well, again, you want your
consumption to go up in both periods to
smooth that consumption out.
14:28
So your boss says, next period I'm going to
give you $100.
14:31
So you're going to save 50 less.
14:33
So you can save 50 now and then you're going
to spend 50 more later as well.
14:38
So you're going to increase your consumption
in both periods.
14:41
In order to do that, you need to decrease
your savings again.
14:45
Your savings is your current consumption,
your current income minus your current
consumption. Why one minus C1?
What you see is when Y two goes up, there's
no change in y one, but there's an
increase in C1.
14:58
So savings will go down.
15:01
So those are your income effects.
15:05
Now let's talk about a change in the real
interest rate.
15:08
Now, when there's a change in the real
interest rate, it gets a little more
complicated. The real interest rate is
actually the slope of this
line. It's the slope of the budget
constraint.
15:18
If there's an increase in the real interest
rate, what you're going to see is the slope
of that line is going to get steeper.
15:26
As there's an increase in the real interest
rate, there's an incentive to
substitute away from C one towards C two.
15:35
So we'll talk a bit more about that in a
second.
15:37
But right here at this point, this point is,
you know, borrowing and no lending point.
15:41
So that says if you spend everything you
have in the first period, your wealth and
your income in the first period, you save
nothing and you just spend everything you
earn in the second period, your second
period income in the second period.
15:55
So if that's the case, it doesn't depend on
the real interest rate.
15:58
Every other point along that line does.
16:01
Every other level of consumption depends
upon the real interest rate.
16:05
So the real interest rate represents the
opportunity cost of
consuming now in terms of foregone
consumption in the future.
16:14
So again, opportunity cost, that's the cost.
16:17
Those are the costs you give up in order to
do something.
16:20
Whatever you give up in order to do
something, those are your opportunity costs.
16:25
So let's say that one more time, the real
interest rate is your opportunity cost of
consuming now in terms of foregone
consumption in the future.
16:34
So if you have $100 and the real interest
rate is 10%, if you
spend that $100 now, you're going to miss
out on $110 of
consumption in the second period.
16:44
You get your $100 back and you get the 10%
interest.
16:49
So as the interest rate goes up, you have
more incentive to save now,
consume less now so that you can consume
more later.
16:58
So you see that line gets steeper, it moves
away from C one and it
moves towards C two.
17:05
So if we take a look at our arrows, put it
in arrow form again, as the real interest
rate goes up, consumption in the first
period goes down, consumption in the second
period goes up, and we save more money.
17:17
We get a higher return on our savings, so we
save more money.
17:23
All right. So we also have what's called the
wealth effect.
17:25
When there's a change in the real interest
rate, it depends on the type of person.
17:30
All right. Whether you're a net borrower or
whether you're a net saver, a net borrower,
that's somebody who has liabilities greater
than assets.
17:38
You owe money to the bank, say, more than
they owe you.
17:41
So you owe them more on a loan than you have
in your savings account.
17:45
Well, you pay real interest on that loan.
17:49
So as the real interest rate goes up, you're
effectively poorer.
17:52
If you're effectively poor, you're going to
spend less money, not in one period, but
both periods, because again, we want to
smooth out our consumption.
18:01
So see one and see two are going to go down
for the net borrower.
18:05
Your savings are going to go up.
18:07
You're going to save more of your income in
order to pay off your loan.
18:12
Again, savings is Y one minus C, one y one's
not changing
here. C one is going down.
18:19
So savings is going up.
18:21
Now a net saver, that's somebody the bank
owes the person more than they owe the bank.
18:26
They have they have assets greater than
their liabilities.
18:29
Maybe somebody that's further on in life and
has, say, $1,000,000 sitting in the bank
and the interest rate doubles.
18:36
Well, now his wealth sitting in the bank is
accumulating at a faster
rate. He's effectively richer.
18:43
So he's going to consume more and.
18:45
Both periods to smooth out US consumption.
18:48
That means the savings are going to go down.
18:50
Why? One isn't changing.
18:52
He's not making more money at work, but his
wealth is growing.
18:56
So as wealth is growing, you say, Hey, I
don't need to save this money I'm making.
19:00
I'm going to go out and buy myself fancy
cars.
19:02
I don't need to worry about it. I don't need
to save for retirement.
19:05
So why one minus C one is going to go up or
I'm sorry, y one minus
C one is going to go down.
19:11
I apologize. Savings will decrease.
19:15
All right. Now, we also have what's called
the net effect.
19:18
So the net effect is just a combination of
the substitution effect
and the wealth effect for a change in the
real interest rate.
19:27
So you've already done all the work from
this.
19:29
This should be easy for you.
19:30
Now you just combine the effects from the
substitution effect and the wealth effect.
19:35
So let's take a look at it for the net
borrower.
19:37
When there's an increase in the real
interest rate from the substitution effect.
19:41
You want to consume less in the first period
for the wealth effect.
19:45
When there's an increase in the real
interest rate, the net borrower is poor.
19:49
He wants to spend less in the first period.
19:51
Both arrows are going down from those
effects.
19:54
So the net effect, the arrow goes down now
for C
to the substitution effect for the net,
borrower goes up, the wealth
effect goes down.
20:04
So we put a question mark without more
information, we don't know which effect
dominates. So we put that question mark
there to say, hey, I don't know.
20:12
All right. For savings in both the wealth
effect
and the substitution effect, the arrows
pointing up, you're saving more.
20:21
So the net effect, we know the net borrower
is saving more
for the net saver, an increase in the real
interest rate.
20:29
It's the same effects as the net borrower
for the substitution effect.
20:32
You want to spend less in the first period
as the same as the real interest rate goes
up. But for the net saver is the real
interest rate goes up.
20:41
You want to spend more by the wealth effect,
so the arrows are going in opposite
directions. So again, we don't know which
effect dominates.
20:49
We do know for C2 what's going to happen for
both the substitution
effect and the wealth effect.
20:55
The net saver wants to spend more in the
second period, so the arrow points
up for savings for the net saver.
21:04
The arrows are going in opposite directions.
21:06
All right. So for an increase in the real
interest rate, he wants to save more by the
substitution effect, but an increase in the
real interest rate for the wealth effect he
wants to save less.
21:16
So it's ambiguous.
21:18
We don't know. So we put a question mark.
21:21
So that is our presentation on consumption
and savings.
21:25
Using the two period consumer model, we
learned how to define savings.
21:29
We learned why people save.
21:31
We learned about the relationship between
savings and consumption.
21:34
We learned how changes in income effect,
affect the relationship between
savings and consumption.
21:40
And we also learn how changes in the real
interest rate affect the relationship between
savings and consumption.
21:46
Thank you.